Basisinkomen en geluk: een doel voor de hele mensheid

Black
Agenda Report bracht vorige week woensdag een artikel, eerder gepubliceerd op Truthdig en geschreven door Ellen Brown, waarin zij betoogt dat een universeel basisinkomen (UBI) geen probleem is en niet ten koste zal gaan van belastingverhogingen voor de hogere of de middeninkomens. 

Het betreft hier een uiterst intelligent schrijven van Brown, een artikel dat van groot belang kan zijn voor iedereen op onze kleine aarde: het uitroeien van armoede en een oplossing voor de tijd dat machines en computers het overgrote deel van de arbeid die de mens verricht zullen overnemen. 

Praatjes dat de automatisering alleen maar meer banen zullen opleveren, zijn volkomen naast de waarheid…… Neem de betaalautomaten: deze automaten hebben duizenden bankmedewerkers de baan als loketmedewerker gekost….. Of wat dacht je van de automatisering in de landbouw, werk dat vroeger door tienduizenden arbeiders werd gedaan, kan nu in veel gevallen zelfs met 2 machines worden verricht, het in de grond stoppen van zaden en de oogst…… 

Met een basisinkomen kunnen we eindelijk aan het geluk van de mens werken, wel zal men daarvoor in het onderwijs ruimte vrij moeten maken voor lessen hoe om te gaan met vrije tijd, iets waar mensen niet goed in zijn en waar de meesten van ons pas achter komen bij werkloosheid en na pensionering….. (en dat is toch uitermate triest…)

Lees het volgende artikel en geeft het door:

Universal
Basic Income Is Easier Than It Looks

Universal Basic Income Is Easier Than It Looks

Ellen
Brown
09
Jan 2019

A
universal income program can help correct the debt bubble problem
without fear of “overheating” the economy.

It
could actually be funded year after year without driving up taxes or
prices.”


Calls
for a Universal Basic Income (UBI) have been increasing, most
recently as part of the “Green New Deal” (GND) introduced by Rep.
Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez, D-N.Y., and 
supported
in the last month 
by
at least 40 members of Congress. A UBI is a monthly payment to all
adults with no strings attached, similar to Social Security. 
Critics
say
 the
Green New Deal asks too much of the rich and upper-middle-class
taxpayers who will have to pay for it, but taxing the rich is
not 
what
the resolution proposes 
.
It says funding would primarily come from the federal government,
“using a combination of the Federal Reserve, a new public bank or
system of regional and specialized public banks,” among other
vehicles.

The
Federal Reserve alone could do the job. It could buy “Green”
federal bonds with money created on its balance sheet, just as the
Fed funded the purchase of $3.7 trillion in bonds in its
“quantitative easing” program to save the banks. The Treasury
could also do it. The Treasury has the constitutional power to issue
coins in any denomination, 
even
trillion dollar coins 
.
What prevents legislators from pursuing those options is the fear of
hyperinflation from excess “demand” (spendable income) driving
prices up. But in fact the consumer economy is chronically short of
spendable income, due to the way money enters the consumer economy.
We actually 
needregular
injections of money to avoid a “balance sheet recession” and
allow for growth, and a UBI is one way to do it.

Funding
would primarily come from the federal government, “using a
combination of the Federal Reserve, a new public bank or system of
regional and specialized public banks,”

The
pros and cons of a UBI are hotly debated and have been 
discussed
elsewhere 
.
The point here is to show that it could actually be funded year after
year without driving up taxes or prices.New money is continually
being added to the money supply, but it is added as debt created
privately by banks. (How banks, rather than the government, create
most of the money supply today is explained on the Bank of England
website 
here .)
A UBI would replace money-created-as-debt with debt-free money—a
“debt jubilee” for consumers—while leaving the money supply for
the most part unchanged; and to the extent that new money was added,
it could help create the demand needed to fill the gap between actual
and potential productivity.

The
Debt Overhang Crippling Economies

The
“bank money” composing most of the money in circulation is
created only when someone borrows, and today businesses and consumers
are burdened with debts that are higher than ever before. In 2018,
credit card debt alone exceeded $1 trillion, student debt exceeded
$1.5 trillion, auto loan debt exceeded $1.1 trillion, and
non-financial corporate debt hit $5.7 trillion. When businesses and
individuals pay down old loans rather than taking out new loans, the
money supply shrinks, causing a “balance sheet recession.” In
that situation, the central bank, rather than removing money from the
economy (as the Fed is doing now), needs to add money to fill the gap
between debt and the spendable income available to repay it.

Debt
always grows faster than the money available to repay it. 
One
problem is the interest 
,
which is not created along with the principal, so more money is
always owed back than was created in the original loan. Beyond that,
some of the money created as debt is 
held
off the consumer market by “savers” 
and
investors who place it elsewhere, making it unavailable to companies
selling their wares and the wage-earners they employ. The result is a
debt bubble that continues to grow until it is not sustainable and
the system collapses, in the familiar death spiral euphemistically
called the “business cycle.” As economist Michael Hudson shows in
his 2018 book, “

and Forgive Them Their Debts 
,” this
inevitable debt overhang was corrected historically with periodic
“debt jubilees”—debt forgiveness—something he argues we need
to do again today.

For
governments, 
a
debt jubilee could be effected 
by
allowing the central bank to buy government securities and hold them
on its books. For individuals, one way to do it fairly across the
board would be with a UBI.

Why
a UBI Need Not Be Inflationary

In
a 2018 book called “
The
Road to Debt Bondage: How Banks Create Unpayable Debt 
,”
political economist Derryl Hermanutz proposes a central-bank-issued
UBI of $1,000 per month, credited directly to people’s bank
accounts. Assuming this payment went to all U.S. residents over 18,
or about 250 million people, the outlay would be about $2.5 trillion
annually. For people with overdue debt, Hermanutz proposes that it
automatically go to pay down those debts. 
Since
money is created as loans and extinguished when they are repaid, that
portion of a UBI disbursement would be extinguished along with the
debt
.

People
who were current on their debts could choose whether or not to pay
them down, but many would also no doubt go for that option. Hermanutz
estimates that roughly half of a UBI payout could be extinguished in
this way through mandatory and voluntary loan repayments. That money
would not increase the money supply or demand. It would just allow
debtors to spend on necessities with debt-free money rather than
hocking their futures with unrepayable debt.

He
estimates that another third of a UBI disbursement would go to
“savers” who did not need the money for expenditures. This money,
too, would not be likely to drive up consumer prices, since it would
go into investment and savings vehicles rather than circulating in
the consumer economy. That leaves only about one-sixth of payouts, or
$400 billion, that would actually be competing for goods and
services; and that sum could easily be absorbed by the “output gap”
between actual and forecasted productivity.

$2
trillion could be injected into the economy 
every
year
 without
creating price inflation.”

According
to a July 2017 paper from the Roosevelt Institute called “
What
Recovery? The Case for Continued Expansionary Policy at the Fed 
”:
“GDP remains well below both the long-run trend and the level
predicted by forecasters a decade ago. In 2016, real per capita GDP
was 10% below the Congressional Budget Office’s (CBO) 2006
forecast, and shows no signs of returning to the predicted level.”

The
report showed that the most likely explanation for this lackluster
growth was inadequate demand. Wages have remained stagnant; and
before producers will produce, they need customers knocking on their
doors.

In
2017, the U.S. Gross Domestic Product was $19.4 trillion. If the
economy is running at 10 percent below full capacity, $2 trillion
could be injected into the economy 
every
year
 without
creating price inflation. It would just generate the demand needed to
stimulate an additional $2 trillion in GDP. In fact a UBI might pay
for itself, just as the 
G.I.
Bill produced a sevenfold return 
from
increased productivity after World War II.

The
Evidence of China

That
new money can be injected year after year without triggering price
inflation is evident from a look at China. In the last 20 years, its
M2 money supply has grown from just over 10 trillion yuan to 80
trillion yuan ($11.6T), a nearly 800 percent increase. Yet the
inflation rate of its Consumer Price Index (CPI) remains 
a
modest 2.2 percent
.

Why
has all that excess money not driven prices up? The answer is that
China’s Gross Domestic Product has grown at the same fast clip as
its money supply. When supply (GDP) and demand (money) increase
together, prices remain stable.

Whether
or not the Chinese government would approve of a UBI, 
it
does recognize 
that
to stimulate productivity, the money must get out there 
first;
and since the government owns 80 percent of China’s banks, it is in
a position to borrow money into existence as needed. For
“self-funding” loans—those that generate income (fees for rail
travel and electricity, rents for real estate)—repayment
extinguishes the debt along with the money it created, leaving the
net money supply unchanged. When loans are not repaid, the money they
created is not extinguished; but if it goes to consumers and
businesses that then buy goods and services with it, demand will
still stimulate the production of supply, so that supply and demand
rise together and prices remain stable.

Without
demand, producers will not produce and workers will not get hired,
leaving them without the funds to generate supply, in a vicious cycle
that leads to recession and depression. And that cycle is what our
own central bank is triggering now.

The
Fed Tightens the Screws

Rather
than stimulating the economy with new demand, the Fed has been
engaging in “quantitative tightening.” On Dec. 19, 2018, it
raised the Fed funds rate for the ninth time in three years, despite
a “brutal” stock market in which the Dow Jones Industrial Average
had already lost 3,000 points in 2 ½ months. The Fed is still
struggling to reach even its modest 2 percent inflation target, and
GDP growth is trending down, with estimates at only 2-2.7 percent for
2019. So why did it again raise rates, 
over
the protests 
of
commentators, including the president himself?

For
its barometer, the Fed looks at whether the economy has hit “full
employment,” which it considers to be 4.7 percent unemployment,
taking into account the “natural rate of unemployment” of people
between jobs or voluntarily out of work. At full employment, workers
are expected to demand more wages, causing prices to rise. But
unemployment is now officially at 3.7 percent—
beyond technical
full employment—and neither wages nor consumer prices have shot up.
There is obviously something wrong with the theory, as is evident
from a 
look
at Japan 
,
where prices have long refused to rise despite a serious lack of
workers.

The
official unemployment figures are actually misleading. Including
short-term discouraged workers, the rate of U.S. unemployed or
underemployed workers as of May 2018 was 7.6 percent, 
double
the widely reported rate 
.
When long-term discouraged workers are included, 
the
real unemployment figure was 21.5 percent 
.
Beyond that large untapped pool of workers, there is the seemingly
endless supply of cheap labor from abroad and the expanding labor
potential of robots, computers and machines. In fact, the economy’s
ability to generate supply in response to demand is far from reaching
full capacity today.

When
long-term discouraged workers are included, the real unemployment
figure was 21.5 percent.”

Our
central bank is driving us into another recession based on bad
economic theory. Adding money to the economy for productive,
non-speculative purposes will not drive up prices so long as
materials and workers (human or mechanical) are available to create
the supply necessary to meet demand; and they are available now.
There will always be price increases in particular markets when there
are shortages, bottlenecks, monopolies or patents limiting
competition, but these increases are not due to an economy awash with
money. Housing, health care, education and gas have all gone up, but
it is not because people have too much money to spend. In fact it is
those necessary expenses that are driving people into unrepayable
debt, and it is this massive debt overhang that is preventing
economic growth.

Without
some form of debt jubilee, the debt bubble will continue to grow
until it can again no longer be sustained. A UBI can help correct
that problem without fear of “overheating” the economy, so long
as the new money is limited to filling the gap between real and
potential productivity and goes into generating jobs, building
infrastructure and providing for the needs of the people, rather than
being diverted into the speculative, parasitic economy that feeds off
them.

Ellen
Brown is an attorney, chairman of the Public Banking Institute, and
author of twelve books including “Web of Debt” and “The
Public Bank Solution.”

This
article previously appeared in 
Truthdig .

COMMENTS?

Please
join the conversation on Black Agenda Report’s Facebook page at
http://facebook.com/blackagendareport

Or,
you can comment by emailing us at comments@blackagendareport.com

IMF tegen Grieken: sorry we gaan jullie land vernietigen…………..

Op 11 april jl. berichtte ik al over de nieuwe maatregelen die Griekenland moet treffen, onder druk van de trojka, bestaande uit de Europese Centrale Bank (ECB), de Europese Commissie en het IMF.

Griekenland heeft de zeggenschap over haar staatseigendommen, die het nog in bezit had, af moeten staan aan het Europees Stabiliteitsmechanisme (ESM). Dit niet democratisch gekozen orgaan kan desgewenst deze eigendommen voor een appel en een ei verkopen, zoals Griekenland al eigendommen zwaar onder de prijs heeft moeten verkopen…..

De pensioenen worden verder gekort, terwijl het grootste deel van de ouderen in Griekenland daar amper of niet van rond kan komen…… Daarnaast worden de lonen verder verlaagd, ook hier geldt, dat veel Grieken al onder het minimumloon verdienen, althans als ze regelmatig betaald worden, ook daar wil het nog wel eens aan ontbreken…… Zelfs terminale patiënten kunnen in Griekenland veelal niet aan medicijnben komen, daar ze het geld ontbreekt……..

Zoals Michael Hudson in het Information Clearing House artikel hieronder betoogt: de gewone Griek had part nog deel aan de leningen die Griekenland, totaal onverantwoord werden verstrekt, o.a. door banken en andere financiële instellingen in het NW van Europa (plus Frankrijk). Ook het IMF, onderdeel van de trojka schijnt Griekenland enorme bedragen op de pof te hebben geleend. Terwijl het IMF, maar ook de ECB hadden moeten toezien op verantwoorde kredietverlening. trekken ze nu het mis is gegaan, de gewone burger het vel over de oren….

PvdA hufter Dijsselbloem, de plaag van de Grieken, is mede verantwoordelijk voor de enorme ellende waarin Griekenland zich bevindt. Nog steeds betaalt Griekenland zich helemaal scheel aan rentebetalingen, terwijl de rente bijna op nul staat…… Voorts vindt Dijsselbloem het normaal dat grote Griekse bedrijven de belasting in eigen land ontduiken in……. Nederland!!!

De Griekse regering had volgens Hudson geen andere optie dan akkoord te gaan met de breidel van de vermaledijde trojka, dit daar men anders het Griekse bankensysteem zou hebben laten ploffen……

Overigens is het niet ondenkbaar, dat de regering van Griekenland de wacht is aangezegd, niet in zee te gaan met de Russen, waar even sprake van was, daar het Griekse leger dan met behulp van NAVO troepen een coup zou hebben gepleegd…….

Eén ding is zeker, zonder de EU had Griekenland niet zo in de stront gezeten…..

Mensen het kan nog veel erger en smeriger (wat betreft o.a. het IMF), lees het volgende artikel, een verslag van de video die u hieronder ziet (onder de geschreven versie, kan u klikken voor een ‘Dutch vertaling’):

IMF to
Greece: Sorry We’ll Destroy You


Bond
holders, banks, and IMF bear responsibility for having made
irresponsible loans to Greece, so it is not right for them to force
yet more austerity on Greece, says Michael Hudson.



By
Michael Hudson



May
10, 2017 “Information
Clearing House
” – Sharmini Peries: It’s the Real News
Network. I am Sharmini Peries coming to you from Baltimore. The
European Commission announced on May 2, that an agreement on Greek
pension and income tax reforms would pave the way for further
discussions on debt release for Greece. The European Commission
described this as good news for Greece. The Greek government
described the situation in similar terms. However, little attention
has been given as to how the wider Greek population are experiencing
the consequences of the policies of the Troika. On May Day thousands
of Greeks marked International Workers Day with anti-austerity
protests. One of the protester’s 
a 32-year-old lawyer perhaps
summed the mood, the best when he said …

Speaker
2: “The current Greek government, like all the ones before it, have
implemented measures that has only one goal, the crushing of the
workers, the working class and everyone who works themselves to the
bone. We are fighting for the survival of the poorest who need help
the most.”

Sharmini
Peries: To discuss the most recent negotiations underway between
Greece and the TROIKA, which is a European Central Bank, the EU and
the IMF, here’s Michael Hudson. Michael is a distinguished research
professor of Economics at the University of Missouri, Kansas City. He
is the author of many books including, “Killing the Host: How
Financial Parasites and Debt Bondage the Global Economy” and most
recently “J is for Junk Economics: A Survivor’s Guide to Economic
Vocabulary in the Age of Deception”. Michael it’s been a while,
good to have you back.

Michael
Hudson: Good to be here.


Sharmini
Peries: Michael, let’s start with what’s being negotiated at the
moment.


Michael
Hudson: I wouldn’t call it a negotiation. Greece is simply being
dictated to. There is no negotiation at all. It’s been told that
its economy has shrunk so far by 20%, but has to shrink another 5%
making it even worse than the depression. Its wages have fallen and
must be cut by another 10%. Its pensions have to be cut back.
Probably 5 to 10% of its population of working age will have to
immigrate.

The
intention is to cut the domestic tax revenues (not raise them),
because labor won’t be paying taxes and businesses are going out of
business. So we have to assume that the deliberate intention is to
lower the government’s revenues by so much that Greece will have to
sell off even more of its public domain to foreign creditors.
Basically it’s a smash and grab exercise, and the role of Tsipras
is not to represent the Greeks because the Troika have said, “The
election doesn’t matter. It doesn’t matter what the people vote
for. Either you do what we say or we will smash your banking system.”
Tsipras’s job is to say, “Yes I will do 

whatever you want. I want
to stay in power rather than falling in election.”

Sharmini
Peries: Right. Michael you dedicated almost three chapters in your
book “Killing the Host” to how the IMF economists actually knew
that Greece will not be able to pay back its foreign debt, but yet it
went ahead and made these huge loans to Greece. It’s starting to
sound like the mortgage fraud scandal where banks were lending people
money to buy houses when they knew they couldn’t pay it back. Is it
similar?

Michael
Hudson: The basic principle is indeed the same. If a creditor makes a
loan to a country or a home buyer knowing that there’s no way in
which the person can pay, who should bear the responsibility for
this? Should the bad lender or irresponsible bondholder have to pay,
or should the Greek people have to pay?

IMF
economists said that Greece can’t pay, and under the IMF rules it
is not allowed to make loans to countries that have no chance of
repaying in the foreseeable future. The then-head of the IMF,
Dominique Strauss-Kahn, introduced a new rule – the “systemic
problem” rule. It said that if Greece doesn’t repay, this will
cause problems for the economic system – defined as the
international bankers, bondholder’s and European Union budget –
then the IMF can make the loan.

This
poses a question on international law. If the problem is systemic,
not Greek, and if it’s the system that’s being rescued, why
should Greek workers have to dismantle their economy? Why should
Greece, a sovereign nation, have to dismantle its economy in order to
rescue a banking system that is guaranteed to continue to cause more
and more austerity, guaranteed to turn the Eurozone into a dead zone?
Why should Greece be blamed for the bad malstructured European rules?
That’s the moral principle that’s at stake in all this.

Sharmini
Peries: Michael, The New York Times has recently published an article
titled, “IMF torn over whether to bail out Greece again.” It
essentially describes the IMF as being sympathetic towards Greece in
spite of the fact as you say, they knew that Greece could not pay
back this money when it first lent it the money with the Troika.
Right now, the IMF sounds rational and thoughtful about the Greek
people. Is this the case?

Michael
Hudson: Well, Yanis Varoufakis, the finance minister under Syriza,
said that every time he talked to the IMF’s Christine Lagarde and
others two years ago, they were sympathetic. They said, “I am
terribly sorry we have to destroy your economy. I feel your pain, but
we are indeed going to destroy your economy. There is nothing we can
do about it. We are only following orders.” The orders were coming
from Wall Street, from the Eurozone and from investors who bought or
guaranteed Greek bonds.


Being
sympathetic, feeling their pain doesn’t really mean anything if the
IMF says, “Oh, we know it is a disaster. We are going to screw you
anyway, because that’s our job. We are the IMF, after all. Our job
is to impose austerity. Our job is to shrink economies, not help them
grow. Our constituency is the bondholders and banks.”

Somebody’s
going to suffer. Should it the wealthy billionaires and the bankers,
or should it be the Greek workers? Well, the Greek workers are not
the IMF’s constituency. It says: “We feel your pain, but we’d
rather you suffer than our constituency.”

So
what you read is simply the usual New York Times hypocrisy,
pretending that the IMF really is feeling bad about what it’s
doing. If its economists felt bad, they would have done what the IMF
European staff did a few years ago after the first loan: They
resigned in protest. They would write about it and go public and say,
“This system is corrupt. The IMF is working for the bankers against
the interest of its member countries.” If they don’t do that,
they are not really sympathetic at all. They are just hypocritical.

Sharmini
Peries: Right. I know that the European Commission is holding up
Greece as an example in order to discourage other member nations in
the periphery of Europe so that they won’t default on their loans.
Explain to me why Greece is being held up as an example.

Michael
Hudson: It’s being made an example for the same reason the United
States went into Libya and bombed Syria: It’s to show that we can
destroy you if you don’t do what we say. If Spain or Italy or
Portugal seeks not to pay its debts, it will meet the same fate. Its
banking system will be destroyed, and its currency system will be
destroyed.

The
basic principle at work is that finance is the new form of warfare.
You can now destroy a country’s economy not merely by invading it.
You don’t even have to bomb it, as you’ve done in the Near East.
All you have to do is withdraw all credit to the banking system,
isolate it economically from making payments to foreign countries so
that you essentially put sanctions on it. You’ll treat Greece like
they’ve treated Iran or other countries.

We
have life and death power over you.” The demonstration effect is
not only to stop Greece, but to stop countries from doing what Marine
Le Pen is trying to do in France: withdraw from the Eurozone.

The
class war is back in business – the class war of finance against
labor, imposing austerity and shrinking living standards, lowering
wages and cutting back social spending. It’s demonstrating who’s
the winner in this economic warfare that’s taking place.

Sharmini
Peries: Then why is the Greek population still supportive of Syriza
in spite of all of this? I mean, literally not only have they, as a
population, been cut to no social safety net, no social security, yet
the Syriza government keeps getting supported, elected in
referendums, and they seem to be able to maintain power in spite of
these austerity measures. Why is that happening?

Michael
Hudson: Well, that’s the great tragedy. They initially supported
Syriza because it promised not to surrender in this economic war.
They said they would fight back. The plan was not pay the debts even
if this led Europe to force Greece out of the European Union.

In
order to do this however, what Yanis Varoufakis and his advisors such
as James Galbraith wanted to do was say, “If we are going not to
pay the debt, we are going to be expelled from the Euro Zone. We have
to have our own currency. We have to have our own banking system.”
But it takes almost a year to put in place your own physical
currency, your own means of reprogramming the ATM machines so that
people can use it, and reprogramming the banking system.

You
also need a contingency plan for when the European Union wrecks the
Greek banks, which basically have been the tool of the oligarchy in
Greece. The government is going to have to take over these banks and
socialize them, and use them for public purposes. Unfortunately,
Tsipras never gave Varoufakis and his staff the go ahead. In effect,
he ended up double crossing them after the referendum two years ago
that said not to surrender. That lead to Varoufakis resigning from
the government.

Tsipras
decided that he wanted to be reelected, and turned out to be just a
politician, realizing that in order to he had to represent the
invader and act as a client politician. His clientele is now the
European Union, the IMF and the bondholders, not the Greeks. What
that means is that if there is an election in Greece, people are not
going to vote for him again. He knows that. He is trying to prevent
an election. But later this month the Greek parliament is going to
have to vote on whether or not to shrink the economy further and cut
pensions even more.

If
there are defections from Tsipras’s Syriza party, there will be an
election and he will be voted out of office. I won’t say out of
power, because he has no power except to surrender to the Troika. But
he’d be out of office. There will probably have to be a new party
created if there’s going to be hope of withstanding the threats
that the European Union is making to destroy Greece’s economy if it
doesn’t succumb to the austerity program and step up its
privatization and sell off even more assets to the bondholders.

Sharmini
Peries: Finally, Michael, why did the Greek government remove the
option of Grexit from the table in order to move forward?

Michael
Hudson: In order to accept the Eurozone. You’re using its currency,
but Greece needs to have its own currency. The reason it

agreed to stay in was
that it had made no preparation for withdrawing. Imagine if you are a
state in the United States and you want to withdraw: you have to have
your own currency. You have to have your own banking system. You have
to have your own constitution. There was no attempt to put real
thought behind what their political program was.

They
were not prepared and still have not taken steps to prepare for what
they are doing. They haven’t made any attempt to justify
non-payment of the debt under International Law: the law of odious
debt, or give a reason why they are not paying.

The
Greek government has not said that no country should be obliged to
disregard its democratic voting, dismantle its public sector and give
up its sovereignty to bondholders. No country should be obliged to
pay foreign creditors if the price of that is shrinking and self
destruction of that economy.

They
haven’t translated this political program of not paying into what
this means in practice to cede sovereignty to the Brussels
bureaucracy, meaning the European Central Bank on behalf of its
bondholders.

Sharmini
Peries: All right Michael, we will keep an eye on this. It looks like
it’s going to get more heated in Greece. At least the people and
the movements are planning to protest this new deal. I thank you so
much for joining us and I hope you can join us again. I understand
you are on your way to Greece in a few weeks and we’ll be expecting
a report back from you about what you find there. Thank You.

Michael
Hudson: Thanks for having me on.

Sharmini
Peries: Thank you for joining us here on the Real News Network.

Note:
Wikipedia defines 
Odious
debt
:

In
international law, odious debt, also known as illegitimate debt, is a
legal doctrine that holds that the national debt incurred by a regime
for purposes that do not serve the best interests of the nation,
should not be enforceable.”

Michael
Hudson is President of The Institute for the Study of Long-Term
Economic Trends (ISLET), a Wall Street Financial Analyst,
Distinguished Research Professor of Economics at the University of
Missouri, Kansas City and author of 
J
is Junk Economics
 (2017), Killing
the Host
 (2015), The
Bubble and Beyond 
(2012) http://michael-hudson.com

Greece
Passes New Austerity for New Loans
,
The Real New Network, May 6, 2017.

Click
for
 SpanishGermanDutchDanishFrench,
translation- Note- 
Translation
may

===========================

Weg met de dictatuur van de EU, NEXIT NU!!



Zie ook:

Drie miljoen Grieken hebben geen ziektekostenverzekering daar ze die niet kunnen betalen……. Dank je wel Dijsselbloem (PvdA)…….‘ (veel patiënten kunnen niet eens benodigde medicatie als pijnstillers en chemo kuren betalen…..)

Radio1 met onvervalste anti-Griekse propaganda……..

Paul Tang met kritiek op beleid PvdA partijcollega Dijsselbloem t.a.v. Griekenland…………

EU vluchtelingenbeleid is een ‘groot succes’ zo merken de vluchtelingen in Griekenland……..

Belastingontduiking/ontwijking kost de belastingbetalers wereldwijd honderden miljarden op jaarbasis……

Terzijde om de macht van bedrijven over regeringen te laten zien:

Wereldbank laat weer eens het ware, uiterst inhumane neoliberale gezicht zien: El Salvador wordt gedwongen miljarden te betalen aan groot vervuiler OceanaGold…..

Henk Nijboer (PvdA Tweede Kamer) is niet tegen ‘rulings….’

Jeroen Dijsselbloem (PvdA) wilde Griekse collega aanvallen bij nieuwe afspraken tot het verder in het pak naaien van Grieken…….



Klik voor meer berichten n.a.v. het bovenstaande, op één van de labels, die u hieronder aantreft.

Terrorisme minder bedreigend dan ons financiële systeem!!

Ons financiële systeem is een veel groter gevaar dan terrorisme, betoogt Paul Craig Roberts. In een artikel op Information Clearing House beschrijft hij m.n. de situatie in de VS, maar zoals u begrijpt, is deze hier niet anders. Voor een vertaling kunt u onder het volgende artikel klikken, dit neemt wel enige tijd in beslag:

The
Financial System Is A Larger Threat Than Terrorism

By
Paul Craig Roberts

March
08, 2016 “
Information
Clearing House

– In the 21st century Americans have been distracted by the
hyper-expensive “war on terror.” Trillions of dollars have been
added to the taxpayers’ burden and many billions of dollars in
profits to the military/security complex in order to combat
insignificant foreign “threats,” such as the Taliban, that remain
undefeated after 15 years. All this time the financial system,
working hand-in-hand with policymakers, has done more damage to
Americans than terrorists could possibly inflict.

The
purpose of the Federal Reserve and US Treasury’s policy of zero
interest rates is to support the prices of the over-leveraged and
fraudalent financial instruments that unregulated financial systems
always create. If inflation was properly measured, these zero rates
would be negative rates, which means not only that retirees have no
income from their retirement savings but also that saving is a losing
proposition. Instead of earning interest on your savings, you pay
interest that shrinks the real value of your saving.

Central
banks, neoliberal economists, and the presstitute financial media
advocate negative interest rates in order to force people to spend
instead of save. The notion is that the economy’s poor economic
performance is not due to the failure of economic policy but to
people hoarding their money. The Federal Reserve and its coterie of
economists and presstitutes maintain the fiction of too much savings
despite the publication of the Federal Reserve’s own report that
52% of Americans cannot raise $400 without selling personal
possessions or borrowing the
money.http://www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/2013-report-economic-well-being-us-households-201407.pdf

Negative
interest rates, which have been introduced in some countries such as
Switzerland and threatened in other countries, have caused people to
avoid the tax on bank deposits by withdrawing their savings from
banks in large denomination bills. In Switzerland, for example,
demand for the 1,000 franc bill (about $1,000) has increased sharply.
These large denomination bills now account for 60% of the Swiss
currency in circulation.

The
response of depositors to negative interest rates has resulted in
neoliberal economists, such as Larry Summers, calling for the
elimination of large denomination bank notes in order to make it
difficult for people to keep their cash balances outside of banks.

Other
neoliberal economists, such as Kenneth Rogoff want to eliminate cash
altogether and have only electronic money. Electronic money cannot be
removed from bank deposits except by spending it. With electronic
money as the only money, financial institutions can use negative
interest rates in order to steal the savings of their depositors.

People
would attempt to resort to gold, silver, and forms of private money,
but other methods of payment and saving would be banned, and
government would conduct sting operations in order to suppress
evasions of electronic money with stiff penalties.

What
this picture shows is that government, economists, and presstitutes
are allied against citizens achieving any financial independence from
personal saving. Policymakers have a crackpot economic policy and
those with control over your life value their scheme more than they
value your welfare.

This
is the fate of people in the so-called democracies. Any remaining
control that they have over their lives is being taken away.
Governments serve a few powerful interest groups whose agendas result
in the destruction of the host economies. The offshoring of middle
class jobs transfers income and wealth from the middle class to the
executives and owners of the corporation, but it also kills the
domestic consumer market for the offshored goods and services. As
Michael Hudson writes, it kills the host. The financialization of the
economy also kills the host and the owners of corporations as well.
When corporate executives borrow from banks in order to boost share
prices and their performance bonuses by buying back the publicly held
stock of the corporations, future profits are converted into interest
payments to banks. The future income streams of the corporations are
financialized. If the future income streams fail, the companies can
be foreclosed, like homeowners, and the banks become the owners of
the corporations.

Between
the offshoring of jobs and the conversion of more and more income
streams into payments to banks, less and less is available to be
spent on goods and services. Thus, the economy fails to grow and
falls into long-term decline. Today many Americans can only pay the
minimum payment on their credit card balance. The result is massive
growth in a balance that can never be paid off. It is these people
who are the least able to service debt who are hit with draconian
charges. The way the credit card companies have it now, if you make
one late payment or your payment is returned by your bank, you are
hit for the next six months with a Penalty Annual Percentage Rate of
29.49%.

In
Europe entire countries are being foreclosed. Greece and Portugal
have been forced into liquidation of national assets and the social
security systems. So many women have been forced into poverty and
prostitution that the hourly price of a prostitute has been driven
down to $4.12.

Throughout
the Western world the financial system has become an exploiter of the
people and a deadweight loss on economies. There are only two
possible solutions. One is to break the large banks up into smaller
and local entities such as existed prior to the concentration that
deregulation fostered. The other is to nationalize them and operate
them solely in the interest of the general welfare of the population.

The
banks are too powerful currently for either solution to occur. But
the greed, fraud, and self-serving behavior of Western financial
systems, aided and abeted by governments, could be leading to such a
breakdown of economic life that the idea of a private financial
system will become as abhorent in the future as Nazism is today.

Dr.
Paul Craig Roberts 
was
Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for Economic Policy and associate
editor of the Wall Street Journal. He was columnist for Business
Week, Scripps Howard News Service, and Creators Syndicate. He has had
many university appointments. His internet columns have attracted a
worldwide following. Roberts’ latest books are The
Failure of Laissez Faire Capitalism and Economic Dissolution of the
West
How
America Was Lost
, andThe
Neoconservative Threat to World Order
.

Click
for
 SpanishGermanDutchDanishFrench,
translation- Note- 
Translation
may take a moment to load.

Klik voor meer berichten n.a.v. het voorgaande, op één van de labels, die u onder dit bericht terugvindt, dit geldt niet voor het label ‘Rogoff’.

VS dwarsboomt Rusland en China via het IMF en de Wereldbank, terreur op een ander niveau……

De VS dwarsboomt Rusland en China: Oekraïne is het eerste land, dat zegt een lening van Rusland niet terug te betalen, ook al was één van de condities voor die lening 5% rente, veel gunstiger dan die van het IMF en de Wereldbank….. Oekraïne was het eerste land, dat stelde een schuld van 3 miljard dollar aan de Russen niet terug te betalen….. China en Rusland varen een steeds onafhankelijker koers op financieel gebied, als tegenhangers van het uiterst asociale, inhumane, neoliberale aandelenkapitalisme, dat in feite wordt geleid vanuit de VS, via het IMF en de Wereldbank, waarbij de belangen van de VS en haar munt altijd voorop gaan……

Daar de VS feitelijk aan de touwen trekt bij het IMF en de Wereldbank, besloot het IMF niet langer garant te staan voor leningen, die bijvoorbeeld Rusland aan andere landen heeft verstrekt, zoals de hiervoor aangeduide lening van 3 miljard dollar aan Oekraïne. Met andere woorden maande het IMF deze landen en in dit voorbeeld Oekraïne, de lening van Rusland simpelweg niet terug te betalen!! Sterker nog: voorwaarde voor een lening van het IMF, is het niet terugbetalen van schulden aan Rusland of China……. Hiervoor  moest het IMF de regels tijdens het spel aanpassen, een schoftenstreek van enorme grootte!! Oekraïne was normaal gesproken niet zo maar in aanmerking gekomen voor een lening van het IMF of de Wereldbank, vanwege de bestaande schuld aan Rusland, maar kan nu gewoon miljarden extra lenen en het eerder geleende geld in de zak steken.

Voor een lening van het IMF en de Wereldbank moet wel een fiks deel van de soevereiniteit worden ingeleverd en zal het land het neoliberale systeem moeten invoeren, waarbij de bevolking uiteraard de klos is, zoals de Grieken dat nu dagelijks merken: leven in armoede en zelfs met een baan, zullen velen in armoede blijven steken, daar de salarissen gigantisch naar beneden werden bijgesteld…….. Uiteraard moeten zoveel mogelijk staatseigendommen worden verkocht, zoals openbare nutsvoorzieningen, waar mensen bijvoorbeeld veel meer zullen moeten betalen voor water, de gezondheidszorg en scholing……..

Hier het artikel van Information Clearing House, waarin e.e.a. uit de doeken wordt gedaan, een lang artikel, maar uiterst verhelderend:

The
IMF Changes its Rules to Isolate China and Russia

By
Michael Hudson – Guns
and Butter

Dr.
Hudson discusses his paper, The IMF Changes Its Rules To Isolate
China and Russia; implications of the four policy changes at the
International Monetary Fund in its role as enforcer of
inter-government debts; the Shanghai Cooperation Organization (SCO)
as an alternative military alliance to NATO; the Asian Infrastructure
Investment Bank (AIIB) threatens to replace the IMF and World Bank;
the Trans Pacific Partnership Treaty; the China International
Payments System (CIPS); WTO investment treaties; Ukraine and Greece;
different philosophies of development between east and west; break up
of the post WWII dollarized global financial system; the world
dividing into two camps.

Posted
February 05, 2016

A
New Global Financial Cold War

By
Michael Hudson

A
nightmare scenario of U.S. geopolitical strategists is coming true:
foreign independence from U.S.-centered financial and diplomatic
control. China and Russia are investing in neighboring economies on
terms that cement Eurasian integration on the basis of financing in
their own currencies and favoring their own exports. They also have
created the Shanghai Cooperation Organization (SCO) as an alternative
military alliance to NATO.[1] And
the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB) threatens to replace
the IMF and World Bank tandem in which the United States holds unique
veto power.

More
than just a disparity of voting rights in the IMF and World Bank is
at stake. At issue is a philosophy of development. U.S. and other
foreign investment in infrastructure (or buyouts and takeovers on
credit) adds interest rates and other financial charges to the cost
structure, while charging prices as high as the market can bear
(think of Carlos Slim’s telephone monopoly in Mexico, or the high
costs of America’s health care system), and making their profits
and monopoly rents tax-exempt by paying them out as interest.

By
contrast, government-owned infrastructure provides basic services at
low cost, on a subsidized basis, or freely. That is what has made the
United States, Germany and other industrial lead nations so
competitive over the past few centuries. But this positive role of
government is no longer possible under World Bank/IMF policy. The
U.S. promotion of neoliberalism and austerity is a major reason
propelling China, Russia and other nations out of the U.S. diplomatic
and banking orbit.

On
December 3, 2015, Prime Minister Putin proposed that Russia “and
other Eurasian Economic Union countries should kick-off consultations
with members of the SCO and the Association of Southeast Asian
Nations (ASEAN) on a possible economic partnership.”[2]Russia
also is seeking to build pipelines to Europe through friendly secular
countries instead of Sunni jihadist U.S.-backed countries locked into
America’s increasingly confrontational orbit.

Russian
finance minister Anton Siluanov points out that when Russia’s 2013
loan to Ukraine was made, at the request of Ukraine’s elected
government, Ukraine’s “international reserves were barely enough
to cover three months’ imports, and no other creditor was prepared
to lend on terms acceptable to Kiev. Yet Russia provided $3 billion
of much-needed funding at a 5 per cent interest rate, when Ukraine’s
bonds were yielding nearly 12 per cent.”[3]

What
especially annoys U.S. financial strategists is that this loan by
Russia’s National Wealth Fund was protected by IMF lending
practice, which at that time ensured collectability by withholding
credit from countries in default of foreign official debts, or at
least not bargaining in good faith to pay. To cap matters, the bonds
are registered under London’s creditor-oriented rules and courts.

Most
worrisome to U.S. strategists is that China and Russia are
denominating their trade and investment in their own currencies
instead of dollars. After U.S. officials threatened to derange
Russia’s banking linkages by cutting it off from the SWIFT
interbank clearing system, China accelerated its creation of the
alternative China International Payments System (CIPS), and its own
credit card system to protect Eurasian economies from the threats
made by U.S. unilateralists.

Russia
and China are simply doing what the United States has long done:
using trade and credit linkages to cement their diplomacy. This
tectonic geopolitical shift is a Copernican threat to New Cold War
ideology: Instead of the world economy revolving around the United
States (the Ptolemaic idea of America as “the indispensible
nation”), it may revolve around Eurasia. As long as global
financial control remains grounded in Washington at the offices of
the IMF and World Bank, such a shift in the center of gravity will be
fought with all the power of an American Century (and would-be
American Millennium) inquisition.

Any
inquisition needs a court system and enforcement vehicles. So does
resistance to such a system. That is what today’s global financial,
legal and trade maneuvering is all about. And that is why today’s
world system is in the process of breaking apart. Differences in
economic philosophy call for different institutions.

To
U.S. neocons the specter of AIIB government-to-government investment
creates fear of nations minting their own money and holding each
other’s debt in their international reserves instead of borrowing
dollars, paying interest in dollars and subordinating their financial
planning to the U.S. Treasury and IMF. Foreign governments would have
less need to finance their budget deficits by selling off key
infrastructure. And instead of dismantling public spending, a broad
Eurasian economic union would do what the United States itself
practices, and seek self-sufficiency in banking and monetary policy.

Imagine
the following scenario five years from now. China will have spent
half a decade building high-speed railroads, ports, power systems and
other construction for Asian and African countries, enabling them to
grow and export more. These exports will be coming online to repay
the infrastructure loans. Also, suppose that Russia has been
supplying the oil and gas energy for these projects on credit.

To
avert this prospect, suppose an American diplomat makes the following
proposal to the leaders of countries in debt to China, Russia and the
AIIB: “Now that you’ve got your increased production in place,
why repay? We’ll make you rich if you stiff our adversaries and
turn back to the West. We and our European allies will support your
assigning your nations’ public infrastructure to yourselves and
your supporters at insider prices, and then give these assets market
value by selling shares in New York and London. Then, you can keep
the money and spend it in the West.”

How
can China or Russia collect in such a situation? They can sue. But
what court in the West will accept their jurisdiction?

That
is the kind of scenario U.S. State Department and Treasury officials
have been discussing for more than a year. Implementing it became
more pressing in light of Ukraine’s $3 billion debt to Russia
falling due by December 20, 2015. Ukraine’s U.S.-backed regime has
announced its intention to default. To support their position, the
IMF has just changed its rules to remove a critical lever on which
Russia and other governments have long relied to ensure payment of
their loans.

The
IMF’s role as enforcer of inter-government debts

When
it comes to enforcing nations to pay inter-government debts, the IMF
is able to withhold not only its own credit but also that of
governments and global bank consortia participating when debtor
countries need “stabilization” loans (the neoliberal euphemism
for imposing austerity and destabilizing debtor economies, as in
Greece this year). Countries that do not privatize their
infrastructure and sell it to Western buyers are threatened with
sanctions, backed by U.S.-sponsored “regime change” and
“democracy promotion” Maidan-style. The Fund’s creditor
leverage has been that if a nation is in financial arrears to any
government, it cannot qualify for an IMF loan – and hence, for
packages involving other governments. That is how the dollarized
global financial system has worked for half a century. But until now,
the beneficiaries have been U.S. and NATO lenders, not been China or
Russia.

The
focus on a mixed public/private economy sets the AIIB at odds with
the Trans-Pacific Partnership’s aim of relinquishing government
planning power to the financial and corporate sector, and the
neoliberal aim of blocking governments from creating their own money
and implementing their own financial, economic and environmental
regulation. Chief Nomura economist Richard Koo, explained the logic
of viewing the AIIB as a threat to the U.S.-controlled IMF: “If the
IMF’s rival is heavily under China’s influence, countries
receiving its support will rebuild their economies under what is
effectively Chinese guidance, increasing the likelihood they will
fall directly or indirectly under that country’s influence.”[4]

This
was the setting on December 8, when Chief IMF Spokesman Gerry Rice
announced: “The IMF’s Executive Board met today and agreed to
change the current policy on non-toleration of arrears to official
creditors.” Russian Finance Minister Anton Siluanov accused the IMF
decision of being “hasty and biased.”[5] But
it had been discussed all year long, calculating a range of scenarios
for a sea change in international law. Anders Aslund, senior fellow
at the NATO-oriented Atlantic Council, points out:

The
IMF staff started contemplating a rule change in the spring of 2013
because nontraditional creditors, such as China, had started
providing developing countries with large loans. One issue was that
these loans were issued on conditions out of line with IMF practice.
China wasn’t a member of the Paris Club, where loan restructuring
is usually discussed, so it was time to update the rules.

The IMF
intended to adopt a new policy in the spring of 2016, but the dispute
over Russia’s $3 billion loan to Ukraine has accelerated an
otherwise slow decision-making process.[6]

The
target was not only Russia and its ability to collect on its
sovereign loan to Ukraine, but China even more, in its prospective
role as creditor to African countries and prospective AIIB borrowers,
planning for a New Silk Road to integrate a Eurasian economy
independent of U.S. financial and trade control. The Wall Street
Journal concurred that the main motive for changing the rules was the
threat that China would provide an alternative to IMF lending and its
demands for crushing austerity. “IMF-watchers said the fund was
originally thinking of ensuring China wouldn’t be able to foil IMF
lending to member countries seeking bailouts as Beijing ramped up
loans to developing economies around the world.”[7] So
U.S. officials walked into the IMF headquarters in Washington with
the legal equivalent of suicide vests. Their aim was a last-ditch
attempt to block trade and financial agreements organized outside of
U.S. control and that of the IMF and World Bank.

The
plan is simple enough. Trade follows finance, and the creditor
usually calls the tune. That is how the United States has used the
Dollar Standard to steer Third World trade and investment since World
War II along lines benefiting the U.S. economy. The cement of trade
credit and bank lending is the ability of creditors to collect on the
international debts being negotiated. That is why the United States
and other creditor nations have used the IMF as an intermediary to
act as “honest broker” for loan consortia. (“Honest broker”
means being subject to U.S. veto power.) To enforce its financial
leverage, the IMF has long followed the rule that it will not sponsor
any loan agreement or refinancing for governments that are in default
of debts owed to other governments. However, as the afore-mentioned
Aslund explains, the IMF could easily

change
its practice of not lending into [countries in official] arrears …
because it is not incorporated into the IMF Articles of Agreement,
that is, the IMF statutes. The IMF Executive Board can decide to
change this policy with a simple board majority. The IMF has lent to
Afghanistan, Georgia, and Iraq in the midst of war, and Russia has no
veto right, holding only 2.39 percent of the votes in the IMF. When
the IMF has lent to Georgia and Ukraine, the other members of its
Executive Board have overruled Russia.[8]

After
the rules change, Aslund later noted, “the IMF can continue to give
Ukraine loans regardless of what Ukraine does about its credit from
Russia, which falls due on December 20.[9]

The
IMF rule that no country can borrow if it is in default to a foreign
government was created in the post-1945 world. Since then, the U.S.
Government, Treasury and/or U.S. bank consortia have been party to
nearly every major loan agreement. But inasmuch as Ukraine’s
official debt to Russia’s National Wealth Fund was not to the U.S.
Government, the IMF announced its rules change simply as a
“clarification.” What its rule really meant was that it would not
provide credit to countries in arrears to the U.S. government, not
that of Russia or China.

It
remains up to the IMF board – and in the end, its managing director
– whether or not to deem a country creditworthy. The U.S.
representative can block any foreign leaders not beholden to the
United States. Mikhail Delyagin, Director of the Institute of
Globalization Problems, explained the double standard at work: “The
Fund will give Kiev a new loan tranche on one condition: that Ukraine
should not pay Russia a dollar under its $3 billion debt. … they
will oblige Ukraine to pay only to western creditors for political
reasons.”[10]

The
post-2010 loan packages to Greece are a case in point. The IMF staff
saw that Greece could not possibly pay the sums needed to bail out
French, German and other foreign banks and bondholders. Many Board
members agreed, and have gone public with their whistle blowing.
Their protests didn’t matter. President Barack Obama and Treasury
Secretary Tim Geithner pointed out that U.S. banks had written credit
default swaps betting that Greece could pay, and would lose money if
there were a debt writedown). Dominique Strauss-Kahn backed the hard
line US- European Central Bank position. So did Christine Lagarde in
2015, overriding staff protests.[11]

Regarding
Ukraine, IMF executive board member Otaviano Canuto, representing
Brazil, noted that the logic that “conditions on IMF lending to a
country that fell behind on payments [was to] make sure it kept
negotiating in good faith to reach agreement with
creditors.”[12]Dropping
this condition, he said, would open the door for other countries to
insist on a similar waiver and avoid making serious and sincere
efforts to reach payment agreement with creditor governments.

A
more binding IMF rule is Article I of its 1944-45 founding charter,
prohibiting the Fund from lending to a member state engaged in civil
war or at war with another member state, or for military purposes in
general. But when IMF head Lagarde made the last loan to Ukraine, in
spring 2015, she merely expressed a vapid token hope there might be
peace. Withholding IMF credit could have been a lever to force peace
and adherence to the Minsk agreements, but U.S. diplomatic pressure
led that opportunity to be rejected. President Porochenko immediately
announced that he would step up the civil war with the
Russian-speaking population in the eastern Donbass region.

The
most important IMF condition being violated is that continued warfare
with the East prevents a realistic prospect of Ukraine paying back
new loans. The Donbas is where most Ukrainian exports were made,
mainly to Russia. That market is being lost by the junta’s
belligerence toward Russia. This should have blocked Ukraine from
receiving IMF aid. Aslund himself points to the internal
contradiction at work: Ukraine has achieved budget balance because
the inflation and steep currency depreciation has drastically eroded
its pension costs. But the resulting decline in the purchasing power
of pension benefits has led to growing opposition to Ukraine’s
post-Maidan junta. So how can the IMF’s austerity budget be
followed without a political backlash? “Leading representatives
from President Petro Poroshenko’s Bloc are insisting on massive tax
cuts, but no more expenditure cuts; that would cause a vast budget
deficit that the IMF assesses at 9-10 percent of GDP, that could not
possibly be financed.”[13]

By
welcoming and financing Ukraine instead of treating as an outcast,
the IMF thus is breaking four of its rules:

  1. Not
    to lend to a country that has no visible means to pay back the loan.
    This breaks the “No More Argentinas” rule, adopted after the
    IMF’s disastrous 2001 loan.

  2. Not
    to lend to a country that repudiates its debt to official creditors.
    This goes against the IMF’s role as enforcer for the global
    creditor cartel.

  3. Not
    to lend to a borrower at war – and indeed, to one that is
    destroying its export capacity and hence its balance-of-payments
    ability to pay back the loan.

  4. Finally,
    not to lend to a country that is not likely to carry out the IMF’s
    austerity “conditionalities,” at least without crushing
    democratic opposition in a totalitarian manner.

The
upshot – and new basic guideline for IMF lending – is to split
the world into pro-U.S. economies going neoliberal, and economies
maintaining public investment in infrastructure n and what used to be
viewed as progressive capitalism. Russia and China may lend as much
as they want to other governments, but there is no global vehicle to
help secure their ability to be paid back under international law.
Having refused to roll back its own (and ECB) claims on Greece, the
IMF is willing to see countries not on the list approved by U.S.
neocons repudiate their official debts to Russia or China. Changing
its rules to clear the path for making loans to Ukraine is rightly
seen as an escalation of America’s New Cold War against Russia and
China.

Timing
is everything in such ploys. Georgetown University Law professor and
Treasury consultant Anna Gelpern warned that before the “IMF staff
and executive board [had] enough time to change the policy on arrears
to official creditors,” Russia might use “its notorious debt/GDP
clause to accelerate the bonds at any time before December, or
simply gum up the process of reforming the IMF’s arrears
policy.”[14] According
to this clause, if Ukraine’s foreign debt rose above 60 percent of
GDP, Russia’s government would have the right to demand immediate
payment. But President Putin, no doubt anticipating the bitter fight
to come over its attempts to collect on its loan, refrained from
exercising this option. He is playing the long game, bending over
backward to behave in a way that cannot be criticized as “odious.”

A
more immediate reason deterring the United States from pressing
earlier to change IMF rules was the need to use the old set of rules
against Greece before changing them for Ukraine. A waiver for Ukraine
would have provided a precedent for Greece to ask for a similar
waiver on paying the “troika” – the European Central Bank
(ECB), EU commission and the IMF itself – for the post-2010 loans
that have pushed it into a worse depression than the 1930s. Only
after Greece capitulated to eurozone austerity was the path clear for
U.S. officials to change the IMF rules to isolate Russia. But their
victory has come at the cost of changing the IMF’s rules and those
of the global financial system irreversibly. Other countries
henceforth may reject conditionalities, as Ukraine has done, as well
as asking for write-downs on foreign official debts.

That
was the great fear of neoliberal U.S. and Eurozone strategists last
summer, after all. The reason for smashing Greece’s economy was to
deter Podemos in Spain and similar movements in Italy and Portugal
from pursuing national prosperity instead of eurozone austerity.
“Imagine the Greek government had insisted that EU institutions
accept the same haircut as the country’s private creditors,”
Russian finance minister Anton Siluanov asked. “The reaction in
European capitals would have been frosty. Yet this is the position
now taken by Kiev with respect to Ukraine’s $3 billion eurobond
held by Russia.”[15]

The
consequences of America’s tactics to make a financial hit on Russia
while its balance of payments is down (as a result of collapsing oil
and gas prices) go far beyond just the IMF. These tactics are driving
other countries to defend their own economies in the legal and
political spheres, in ways that are breaking apart the post-1945
global order.

Countering
Russia’s ability to collect in Britain’s law courts

Over
the past year the U.S. Treasury and State Departments have discussed
ploys to block Russia from collecting by suing in the London Court of
International Arbitration, under whose rules Russia’s bonds issued
to Ukraine are registered. Reviewing the excuses Ukraine might use to
avoid paying Russia, Prof. Gelpern noted that it might declare the
debt “odious,” made under duress or corruptly. In a paper for the
Peterson Institute of International Economics (the banking lobby in
Washington) she suggested that Britain should deny Russia the use of
its courts as a means of reinforcing the financial, energy and trade
sanctions passed after Crimea voted to join Russia as protection
against the ethnic cleansing from the Right Sector, Azov Battalion
and other paramilitary groups descending on the region.[16]

A
kindred ploy might be for Ukraine to countersue Russia for
reparations for “invading” it and taking Crimea. Such a claim
would seem to have little chance of success (without showing the
court to be an arm of NATO politics), but it might delay Russia’
ability to collect by tying the loan up in a long nuisance lawsuit.
But the British court would lose credibility if it permits frivolous
legal claims (called barratry in English) such as President
Poroshenko and Prime Minister Yatsenyuk have threatened.

To
claim that Ukraine’s debt to Russia was “odious” or otherwise
illegitimate, “President Petro Poroshenko said the money was
intended to ensure Yanukovych’s loyalty to Moscow, and called the
payment a ‘bribe,’ according to an interview with Bloomberg in
June this year.”[17]The
legal and moral problem with such arguments is that they would apply
equally to IMF and U.S. loans. They would open the floodgates for
other countries to repudiate debts taken on by dictatorships
supported by IMF and U.S. lenders.

As
Foreign Minister Sergei Lavrov noted, the IMF’s change of rules,
“designed to suit Ukraine only, could plant a time bomb under all
other IMF programs.” The new rules showed the extent to which the
IMF is subordinate to U.S. aggressive New Cold Warriors: “since
Ukraine is politically important – and it is only important because
it is opposed to Russia – the IMF is ready to do for Ukraine
everything it has not done for anyone else.”[18]

In
a similar vein, Andrei Klimov, deputy chairman of the Committee for
International Affairs at the Federation Council (the upper house of
Russia’s parliament) accused the United States of playing “the
role of the main violin in the IMF while the role of the second
violin is played by the European Union, [the] two basic sponsors of
the Maidan – the … coup d’état in Ukraine in 2014.”[19]

Putin’s
counter-strategy and the blowback on U.S.-European relations

Having
anticipated that Ukraine would seek excuses to not pay Russia,
President Putin refrained from exercising Russia’s right to demand
immediate payment when Ukraine’s foreign debt rose above 60 percent
of GDP. In November he even offered to defer any payment at all this
year, stretching payments out to “$1 billion next year, $1 billion
in 2017, and $1 billion in 2018,” if “the United States
government, the European Union, or one of the big international
financial institutions” guaranteed payment.[20] Based
on their assurances “that Ukraine’s solvency will grow,” he
added, they should be willing to put their money where their mouth
was. If they did not provide guarantees, Putin pointed out, “this
means that they do not believe in the Ukrainian economy’s future.”

Implicit
was that if the West continued encouraging Ukraine to fight against
the East, its government would not be in a position to pay. The Minsk
agreement was expiring and Ukraine was receiving new arms support
from the United States, Canada and other NATO members to intensify
hostilities against Donbas and Crimea.

But
the IMF, European Union and United States refused to back up the
Fund’s optimistic forecast of Ukraine’s ability to pay in the
face of its continued civil war against the East. Foreign Minister
Lavrov concluded that, “By having refused to guarantee Ukraine’s
debt as part of Russia’s proposal to restructure it, the United
States effectively admitted the absence of prospects of restoring its
solvency.”[21]

In
an exasperated tone, Prime Minister Dmitry Medvedev said on Russian
television: “I have a feeling that they won’t give us the money
back because they are crooks … and our Western partners not only
refuse to help, but they also make it difficult for us.” Accusing
that “the international financial system is unjustly structured,”
he nonetheless promised to “go to court. We’ll push for default
on the loan and we’ll push for default on all Ukrainian debts,”
based on the fact that the loan

was
a request from the Ukrainian Government to the Russian Government. If
two governments reach an agreement this is obviously a sovereign
loan…. Surprisingly, however, international financial organisations
started saying that this is not exactly a sovereign loan. This is
utter bull. Evidently, it’s just an absolutely brazen, cynical lie.
… This seriously erodes trust in IMF decisions. I believe that now
there will be a lot of pleas from different borrower states to the
IMF to grant them the same terms as Ukraine. How will the IMF
possibly refuse them?[22]

And
there the matter stands. On December 16, 2015, the IMF’s Executive
Board ruled that “the bond should be treated as official debt,
rather than a commercial bond.”[23] Forbes
quipped: “Russia apparently is not always blowing smoke. Sometimes
they’re actually telling it like it is.”[24]

Reflecting
the degree of hatred fanned by U.S. diplomacy, U.S.-backed Ukrainian
Finance Minister Natalie A. Jaresko expressed an arrogant confidence
that the IMF would back the Ukrainian cabinet’s announcement on
Friday, December 18, of its intention to default on the debt to
Russia falling due two days later. “If we were to repay this bond
in full, it would mean we failed to meet the terms of the I.M.F. and
the obligations we made under our restructuring.”[25]

Adding
his own bluster, Prime Minister Arseny Yatsenyuk announced his
intention to tie up Russia’s claim for payment by filing a
multibillion-dollar counter claim “over Russia’s occupation of
Crimea and intervention in east Ukraine.” To cap matters, he added
that “several hundred million dollars of debt owed by two state
enterprises to Russian banks would also not be paid.”[26] This
makes trade between Ukraine and Russia impossible to continue.
Evidently Ukraine’s authorities had received assurance from IMF and
U.S. officials that no real “good faith” bargaining would be
required to gain ongoing support. Ukraine’s Parliament did not even
find it necessary to enact the new tax code and budget
conditionalities that the IMF loan had demanded.

The
world is now at war financially, and all that seems to matter is
whether, as U.S. Defense Secretary Donald Rumsfeld had put matters,
“you are for us or against us.” As President Putin remarked at
the 70th session of the UN General Assembly regarding America’s
support of Al Qaeda, Al Nusra and other allegedly “moderate” ISIS
allies in Syria: “I cannot help asking those who have caused this
situation: Do you realize now what you have done? … I am afraid the
question will hang in the air, because policies based on
self-confidence and belief in one’s exceptionality and impunity
have never been abandoned.”[27]

The
blowback

America’s
unilateralist geopolitics are tearing up the world’s economic
linkages that were put in place in the heady days after World War II,
when Europe and other countries were so disillusioned that they
believed the United States was acting out of idealism rather than
national self-interest. Today the question is how long Western Europe
will be willing to forego its trade and investment interests by
accepting U.S.-sponsored sanctions against Russia, Iran and other
economies. Germany, Italy and France already are feeling the strains.

The
oil and pipeline war designed to bypass Russian energy exports is
flooding Europe with refugees, as well as spreading terrorism.
Although the leading issue in America’s Republican presidential
debate on December 15, 2015, was safety from Islamic jihadists, no
candidate thought to explain the source of this terrorism in
America’s alliance with Wahabist Saudi Arabia and Qatar, and hence
with Al Qaeda and ISIS/Daish as a means of destabilizing secular
regimes in Libya, Iraq, Syria, and earlier in Afghanistan. Going back
to the original sin of CIA hubris – overthrowing the secular
Iranian Prime Minister leader Mohammad Mosaddegh in 1953 – U.S.
foreign policy has been based on the assumption that secular regimes
tend to be nationalist and resist privatization and neoliberal
austerity.

Based
on this assumption, U.S. Cold Warriors have aligned themselves
against democratic regimes seeking to promote their own prosperity
and resist neoliberalism in favor of maintaining their own
traditional mixed public/private economies. That is the back-story of
the U.S. fight to control the rest of the world. Tearing apart the
IMF’s rules is only the most recent chapter. Arena by arena, the
core values of what used to be American and European social
democratic ideology are being uprooted by the tactics being used to
hurt Russia, China and their prospective Eurasian allies.

The
Enlightenment’s ideals were of secular democracy and the rule of
international law applied equally to all nations, classical free
market theory (of markets free from unearned income and rent
extraction by special interests), and public investment in
infrastructure to hold down the cost of living and doing business.
These are all now to be sacrificed to a militant U.S. unilateralism.
Putting their “indispensable nation” above the rule of law and
parity of national interests (the 1648 Westphalia treaty, not to
mention the Geneva Convention and Nuremburg laws), U.S. neocons
proclaim that America’s destiny is to prevent foreign secular
democracy from acting in ways other than in submission to U.S.
diplomacy. Behind this lie the special U.S. financial and corporate
interests that control American foreign policy.

This
is not how the Enlightenment was supposed to turn out. Industrial
capitalism a century ago was expected to evolve into an economy of
abundance worldwide. Instead, we have American Pentagon capitalism,
with financial bubbles deteriorating into a polarized rentier economy
and a resurgence of old-fashioned imperialism. If and when a break
comes, it will not be marginal but a seismic geopolitical shift.

The
Dollar Bloc’s Financial Curtain 

By
treating Ukraine’s repudiation of its official debt to Russia’s
National Wealth Fund as the new norm, the IMF has blessed its
default. President Putin and foreign minister Lavrov have said that
they will sue in British courts. The open question is whether any
court exist in the West not under the thumb of U.S. veto?

America’s
New Cold War maneuvering has shown that the two Bretton Woods
institutions are unreformable. It is easier to create new
institutions such as the AIIB than to retrofit the IMF and World
Bank, NATO and behind it, the dollar standard – all burdened with
the legacy of their vested interests.

U.S.
geostrategists evidently thought that excluding Russia, China and
other Eurasian countries from the U.S.-based financial and trade
system would isolate them in a similar economic box to Cuba, Iran and
other sanctioned adversaries. The idea was to force countries to
choose between being impoverished by such exclusion, or acquiescing
in U.S. neoliberal drives to financialize their economies under U.S.
control.

What
is lacking here is the idea of critical mass. The United States may
arm-twist Europe to impose trade and financial sanctions on Russia,
and may use the IMF and World Bank to exclude countries not under
U.S. hegemony from participating in dollarized global trade and
finance. But this diplomatic action is producing an equal and
opposite reaction. That is the Newtonian law of geopolitics. It is
propelling other countries to survive by avoiding demands to impose
austerity on their government budgets and labor, by creating their
own international financial organization as an alternative to the
IMF, and by juxtaposing their own “aid” lending to that of the
U.S.-centered World Bank.

This
blowback requires an international court to handle disputes free from
U.S. arm-twisting. The Eurasian Economic Union accordingly has
created its own court to adjudicate disputes. This may provide an
alternative to Judge Griesa’s New York federal kangaroo court
ruling in favor of vulture funds derailing Argentina’s debt
settlements and excluding that country from world financial markets.

The
more nakedly self-serving U.S. policy is – from backing radical
fundamentalist outgrowths of Al Qaeda throughout the Near East to
right-wing nationalists in Ukraine and the Baltics – then the
greater the pressure will grow for the Shanghai Cooperation
Organization, AIIB and related institutions to break free of the
post-1945 Bretton Woods system run by the U.S. State, Defense and
Treasury Departments and their NATO superstructure of coercive
military bases. As Paul Craig Roberts recently summarized the
dynamic, we are back with George Orwell’s 1984 global fracture
between Oceania (the United States, Britain and its northern European
NATO allies as the sea and air power) vs. Eurasia as the consolidated
land power.

Footnotes:

[1]
The SCO was created in 2001 in Shanghai by the leaders of China,
Russia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, and Uzbekistan. India and
Pakistan are scheduled to join, along with Iran, Afghanistan and
Belarus as observers, and other east and Central Asian countries as
“dialogue partners.”

[2]
Putin
Seeks Alliance to Rival TPP
,” RT.com (December 04 2015). The
Eurasian Economic Union was created in 2014 by Russia, Belarus and
Kazakhstan, soon joined by Kyrgyzstan and Armenia. ASEAN was formed
in 1967, originally by Indonesia, Malaysia the Philippines, Singapore
and Thailand. It subsequently has been expanded. China and the AIIB
are reaching out to replace World Bank. The U.S. refused to join the
AIIB, opposing it from the outset.

[3]
Anton Siluanov, “Russia
wants fair rules on sovereign debt
,” Financial Times, December
10, 2015.

[4]
Richard Koo, “EU
refuses to acknowledge mistakes made in Greek bailout
,” Nomura,
July 14, 2015.

[5]
Ian Talley, “IMF
Tweaks Lending Rules in Boost for Ukraine
,” Wall Street
Journal, December 9, 2015.

[6]
Anders Aslund, “The
IMF Outfoxes Putin: Policy Change Means Ukraine Can Receive More
Loans,” Atlantic Council
, December 8, 2015. On Johnson’s
Russia List, December 9, 2015, #13. Aslund was a major defender of
neoliberal shock treatment and austerity in Russia, and has held up
Latvian austerity as a success story rather than a disaster.

[7]
Ian Talley, op. cit.

[8]
Anders Åslund, “Ukraine
Must Not Pay Russia Back
,” Atlantic Council, November 2, 2015
(from Johnson’s Russia List, November 3, 2015, #50).

[9]
Anders Aslund, “The IMF Outfoxes Putin,” op. cit.

[10]
Quoted in Tamara Zamyantina, “IMF’s dilemma: to help or not to
help Ukraine, if Kiev defaults,” TASS, translated on Johnson’s
Russia List, December 9, 2015, #9.

[11]
I provide a narrative of the Greek disaster in Killing the Host
(2015).

[12]
Reuters, “IMF
rule change keeps Ukraine support; Russia complains
,” December
8, 2015.

[13]
Anders Aslund, “The IMF Outfoxes Putin,” op. cit.

[14]
Anna Gelpern, “Russia’s
Bond: It’s Official! (… and Private … and Anything Else It
Wants to Be …)
,” Credit Slips, April 17, 2015.

[15]
Anton Siluanov, “Russia wants fair rules on sovereign debt,”
Financial Times, op. cit.. He added: “Russia’s financing was not
made for commercial gain. Just as America and Britain regularly do,
it provided assistance to a country whose policies it supported. The
US is now supporting the current Ukrainian government through its
USAID guarantee programme.”

[16]
John Helmer, “IMF
Makes Ukraine War-Fighting Loan, Allows US to Fund Military
Operations Against Russia, May Repay Gazprom Bill
,” Naked
Capitalism, March 16, 2015 (from his site Dances with Bears).

[17]
Ukraine
Rebuffs Putin’s Offer to Restructure Russian Debt
,” Moscow
Times, November 20, 2015, from Johnson’s Russia List, November 20,
2015, #32.

[18]
Lavrov:
U.S. admits lack of prospects of restoring Ukrainian solvency
,”
Interfax, November 7, 2015, translated on Johnson’s Russia List,
December 7, 2015, #38.

[19]
Quoted by Tamara Zamyantina, “IMF’s dilemma,” op. cit.

[20]
Vladimir Putin, “Responses
to journalists’ questions following the G20 summit
,”
Kremlin.ru, November 16, 2015. From Johnson’s Russia List, November
17, 2015,  #7.

Lavrov:
U.S. admits lack of prospects of restoring Ukrainian solvency,”
November 7, 2015, translated on Johnson’s Russia List, December 7,
2015, #38.[21]

In
Conversation with Dmitry Medvedev: Interview with five television
channels
,” Government.ru, December 9, 2015, from Johnson’s
Russia List, December 10, 2015,  #2[22]

[23]
Andrew Mayeda, “IMF
Says Ukraine Bond Owned by Russia Is Official Sovereign Debt
,”
Bloomberg, December 17, 2015.

[24]
Kenneth Rapoza, “IMF
Says Russia Right About Ukraine $3 Billion Loan
,” Forbes.com,
December 16, 2015. The article added: “the Russian government
confirmed to Euroclear, at the request of the Ukrainian authorities
at the time, that the Eurobond was fully owned by the Russian
government.”

[25]
Andrew E. Kramer, “Ukraine
Halts Repayments on $3.5 Billion It Owes Russia
,” The New York
Times, December 19, 2015.

[26]
Roman Olearchyk, “Ukraine
tensions with Russia mount after debt moratorium
,” Financial
Times, December 19, 2015.

[27]
Violence
instead of democracy: Putin slams ‘policies of exceptionalism and
impunity’ in UN speech
,” www.rt.com, September 29, 2015. From
Johnson’s Russia List, September 29, 2015, #2.

http://michael-hudson.com/


Click
for
 SpanishGermanDutchDanishFrench,
translation- Note- 
Translation
may take a moment to load.


Zet dit eens af tegen de enorme berg VS propagandafilms (die Goebbels jaloers zouden maken) waarin de VS altijd de goede partij en het slachtoffer is, neem de film; ‘Jack Ryan: Shadow Recruit’, hierin wordt de VS bijna het slachtoffer van o.a. financiële manipulaties door Rusland…. Uiteraard een belachelijk scenario, zoals in al deze films het geval is, maar wel met de bedoeling de kijkers te hersenspoelen met de idee, dat de de uiterst agressieve VS, dat in een flink deel van de wereld ongekende terreur brengt, de goede partij is, die continu het slachtoffer is van kwade manipulaties door landen als Rusland en China…………

Voor meer berichten n.a.v. het voorgaande, klik op één van de labels,die u onder dit bericht aantreft, dit geldt niet voor de labels: AIIB, ASEAN, Aslund, CIPS, G. Rice, Hudson, Lavrov, SCO en Siluanov. Helaas kan ik maar een beperkt aantal labels plaatsen (maximaal 200 tekens…..).